The dynamic phenomena that appear under non equilibrium economics.
Abstracts/Summary from W. Brian Arthur Complexity Economics: a different framework for economic thought pp 9-11.
W. Brian Arthur describes economics as a vast and complicated set of arrangements and actions wherein agentsâconsumers, firms, banks, investors, government agenciesâbuy and sell, speculate, trade, oversee, bring products into being, offer services, invest in companies, strategize, explore, forecast, compete, learn, innovate, and adapt. In modern parlance we would say it is a massively parallel system of accumulating concurrent behavior. And from all this concurrent behavior differentiation occurs and markets form, prices form, trading arrangements form, institutions and industries form. Aggregate patterns form from accumulative interacting individual behavior, and individual behavior in turn responds to these aggregate patterns: there is a recursive loop of organizational development. The economy is therefore never in a state of equilibrium, but in motion, perpetually âcomputingâ itselfâperpetually inventing itself and constructing itself anew, creating novel structures and possibilities for exploitation, and perpetually open to response.
Arthur describes complexity as the study of the consequences of interactions: the patterns, or structures, or phenomena, that emerge from interactions among elementsâparticles, or cells, or dipoles, or agents, or firms. The study of formationâthe formation of structuresâand how this formation affects the objects causing it. Natural systems complexity studies how changes play out. Or, in other words how behaviour aggregates and propagates through interconnected networks of relationships.
Observing flows in economy or in other domains such as traffic flow one may notice three things:
- A phenomenonâs onset is spontaneous; each instance of it is unique in time of appearance, length of propagation, and time of clearing. It is therefore not easily captured by closed-form solutions, but may be better studied by probabilistic or statistical > and by pattern recognition and association methods.
- A phenomenon is temporal, it emerges or happens within time, and cannot appear if we insist on equilibrium.
- A phenomenon occurs neither at the micro-level (individual car level) nor at the macro-level (overall flow on the road) but at a level in betweenâthe meso-level > and in some cases usefully seen as a bridging of several scales as levels of organization.
Here are examples of phenomena that can be seen when an equilibrium frame or filter is not applied:
- Self-reinforcing asset-price changes (aka bubbles and crashes)
As wins or losses are based on forecast capacity, investors typically generate (or discover) their own forecasting methods, try out promising ones, drop those that donât work, and periodically generate new ones to replace them. The stock price forms from their bids and offers, and thus ultimately from agentsâ forecasts. Our market becomes an ecology of forecasting methods that either succeed or are winnowed out, an ecology that perpetually changes as this happens. And we see several phenomena, chief among them, spontaneous bubbles and crashes. If the price of a stock rises for a while from a first type of forecast, investors will buy in thus validating it, which may cause a further rise. Eventually this drives the price high enough to trigger a second type of forecast. Investors holding these sell, the price drops, which switches off the upward forecasts, causing other investors to sell too, and a crash ensues. The scale and duration of such disruptions vary, they happen randomly in time, so they cannot be predicted. What can be predicted is that such phenomena will occur, and will have certain probability distributions of size and scale. (how does this compare/combine with âself fulfilling prophecyâ?)
- Clustered volatility.
This is the appearance of random periods of low activity followed by periods of high activity. In our artificial market these show up as periods of low and high price volatility. Low volatility reigns when agentsâ forecasts are working reasonably well mutually; then there is little incentive to change them or the results they produce. High volatility happens when some agent or group of agents âdiscoverâ better predictors. This perturbs the overall pattern, so that other investors have to change their predictors to readapt, causing further perturbation and further re-adaptation. The result is a period of intense readjustment or volatility. Such random periods of low volatility alternating with high volatility show up in actual financial market data, where they are called GARCH behavior.
- Sudden percolation.
When a transmissible change happens somewhere in a network, if the network is sparsely connected the change will sooner or later peter out for lack of onward connections. If the network is densely connected, the change will propagate and continue to propagate. In a network of banks, an individual bank might discover it holds distressed assets. It then comes under pressure to increase its liquidity and calls on its counterparty banks. These in turn come under pressure to increase their liquidity and call on their counterparties, and so the distress cascades across the network. Such events can cause serious damage. They peter out in a low-connection network, but propagateâor percolateâfor long periods as the degree of connection passes some point and gets large.
The phenomena illustrated appear and disappear very much in distinct historical time or space, so we will not see them if we insist on equilibrium. And they are localized: they appear in one part of the network or the stock market, possibly to diffuse from there. They operate typically at all scalesânetwork events can involve just a few individual nodes or they can be felt right across the economy. But usually they take place in between the micro and macro, so we can rightly call them meso-phenomena. They are properties of the meso-economy.
And we can see something else. If the degree of interaction in such a system is changed from outside (the probability of events causing further events is increased, say, or more linkages are added), the system will go from few if any consequences to many, and from that to undying-out consequences. It will go through a phase change. All these properties are hallmarks of complexity.
These are phenomena (or orders or structures) that arise in complex systems. Other phenomena have been noticed and others remain to be discovered. Complex system phenomena do not appear until some underlying parameter of the model that depicts the intensity of adjustment or the degree of connection passes some point and reaches some critical level. The overall behavior then undergoes a phase transition. The degree of complexity or transition from simple/equilibrium, to complex and to chaos or multiple equilibrium is a function of the rate of propagation of the change and the capacity to adjust. This is a characteristic of nonequilibrium models. (In this respect we may want to look into the Cynefin model and work on the conditions of transition from one quadrant of the model to another).
The mathematical theory shows that propagations of events causing further events show characteristic properties such as power laws (caused by many and frequent small propagations, few and infrequent large ones), heavy tailed probability distributions (lengthy propagations though rare appear more frequently than normal distributions would predict), and long correlations (events can and do propagate for long distances and times). Such features occur in all systemsâphysical, chemical, biological, geologicalâin which events propagate, so it is not surprising that they occur in our economic examples where propagation is important. They also show up tellingly in actual economic data (Brock et al. 1992; LeBaron et al., 1999).
The mechanisms weâve been looking at arise from self-reinforcing behavior in the interactions, called positive feedback loops. Agents buy into a stock, or disturb a market slightly, or propagate some change, and this causes further buying in, or further disturbance, or further propagation of change. Or as we saw earlier, agents show uncertainty in choice and this causes further uncertainty, or bring on some novel technology and this calls for further novel technologies. Such positive feedbacks disturb the status quo, they cause nonequilibrium. And they cause structures to appear. A small backup in traffic causes further backup and a structure forms, in this case a traffic jam. This is where Brownian motion comes in; it brings perturbations around which small movements nucleate; positive feedback magnifies them and they âlock in,â in time eventually to dissipate.
The presence of positive and negative feedbacks acting together is very much a defining property of complex systems. If a system contains only negative feedbacks (in economics, diminishing returns) it quickly converges to equilibrium and shows âdeadâ behavior. If it contains only positive feedbacks, it runs away and shows explosive behavior. With a mixture of both it shows âinterestingâ or âcomplexâ behavior. With positive feedback interactions add to each other and cause structure, in time to be offset by negative forces and dissipate. Structures then come and go, some stay to be further built on and some lead to further structures. The system is âaliveâ.
These observations add to the earlier literature in economics on positive feedbacks or increasing returns (at the micro-economic, the firmâs level). Here, if a firm (or product or technology or geographical region) gets ahead, possibly by small chance events, given increasing returns it will gain further advantage and get further ahead; it may then subsequently go on to dominate the outcome (Arthur,1989, 1994). The process that increasing returns bring into being is by now well known. Positive feedbacks are however present more widely in the economy than we previously thought: they show up not just with firms or products, but in small mechanisms and large, in decision behavior, market behavior, financial behavior, and network dynamics. They act at all scales to destabilize the economy, even the macro-scale (Keynesâ theory can be seen as positive feedbacks temporarily locking in one of two possible states: full employment and unemployment).
And they lead to a set of characteristic properties: multiple attractors, unpredictability, lock-in, possible inefficiencies, and path-dependence. Their counterparts in physics are multiple metastable states, unpredictability, phase- or mode-locking, high-energy ground states, and non-ergodicity. All properties we associate with formal complexity.
***
One significant task of this project will be to identify the other phenomena at play and find ways to recognize the patterns they form in order to design more effective solutions.
Other Papers by Brian Arthur (to unpack):
Complexity and the Economy (1999)
Inductive reasoning and bounded rationality (1994)
Asset pricing under endogenous expectation in an artificial stock market (1996)
Competing technologies, Increasing returns, and Lock-in (1989)
Process and emergence in the economy (1997)
All systems will be gamed: exploitative behavior in economic and social sysytems (2014)
Positive feedback in the economy (1990)