|
Ignores growth potential ArgumentOpposé1 #231723 A number of critics of the TPC study claim it ignores the potential for major tax reform to increase economic growth through its effect on labor supply and capital formation. They argue such 'macro dynamic' effects make the Romney plan viable without burdening low to middle income earners. | An important aspect of these criticisms is the nature of the model used by the TPC to model tax changes, which assumes away any major impact on labor supply, capital formation or economic growth from reform. The critics argue such 'static' models (including those used by the US Treasury Department and Joint Committee on Taxation) are only suitable for modelling minor incremental changes to the system (see citations below). The excerpt from a paper by Harvey Rosen of Princeton University cited below provides the most detailed statement of this objection of the studies that have been mentioned in the debate. For the objection to hold water the posited macro-dynamic effects would need to be significant. Several attempts have been made to put some numbers on this and to show they make the Romney plan viable. These, along with objections to them, are mapped in the sub-structure to this node. The TPC's defenses against this criticism are also included. |
+Citations (1) - CitationsAjouter une citationList by: CiterankMapLink[1] Growth, Distribution and Tax Reform: Thoughts on the Romney Proposal
En citant: Harvey Rosen - Princeton University Publication info: September 2012 Cité par: Peter Baldwin 6:17 AM 22 October 2012 GMT Citerank: (3) 2317261. RosenProfessor Harvey Rosen of Princeton university maintains the dynamic effects are sufficient to make the Romney plan viable.The crucial step in his analysis is to estimate the boost to GDP the Romney plan would produce using an economic growth model - and then to derive the revenue impact.1198CE71, 232181Rosen - Zero result unwarrantedThe problem with the TPC approach is that, conceding the estimation difficulties, to include no estimate is to implicitly set the dynamic growth effect at zero.13EF597B, 232791Rosen paperGrowth, Distribution and Tax Reform: Thoughts on the Romney Proposal.1198CE71 URL:
| Extrait - At the same time, the TPC model assumes that regardless of the tax rate, people work the same amount, save the same amount, and invest the same amount. Thus, changes in the tax code have no effect on the amount of before-tax income. 4 Because these so-called macro-dynamic behavioral responses are zero, no analysis of tax reform can ever show an increase or decrease in the total level of income in the economy. It follows that the revenue effects of any such changes are constrained to be zero.
What are we to make of this assumption? The first thing to note is that it is not idiosyncratic to the TPC. It is made, for example, by revenue estimators in the Treasury and the Congressional Joint Committee on Taxation. 5 Thus, the TPC has not rigged its modus operandi in order to make the Romney proposal look bad. This observation, though, leaves unanswered the question of whether it is a sensible approach. My own view is that it provides an answer to an interesting question: If one wants to avoid the complications and uncertainties associated with the issue of how taxes affect economic growth, how does a tax reform change the amount of revenue collected and its distribution across income groups? The assumption also provides a measure of consistency when estimating the revenue effects of hundreds of potential changes in the tax law considered by the Congress each year.
That said, one might want to incorporate macro-dynamic behavioral responses into the analysis for several reasons. First, when concerned citizens are looking at tables that purport to show the taxes that would be paid by various income groups under a given tax proposal, they might reasonably expect to see, well, the taxes that would be paid by various income groups under that proposal. Analyses that assume zero macro-dynamic behavioral responses don’t meet that desideratum. Indeed, my highly unscientific survey of professional economists who aren’t tax policy aficionados6 revealed that they were generally incredulous when I told them that the numbers being discussed in the press are based on calculations that explicitly rule out any changes in labor supply or saving behavior.
Second, and relatedly, in the academic literature, it would not be considered exotic or even mildly controversial to include behavioral effects in analyses of tax policy. There is a long tradition of doing so. Indeed, my guess is that it would be challenging to publish a paper on the distribution of the tax burden in a first-rate academic journal if that paper assumed that no one’s labor or savings behavior differed across various tax regimes.
Finally, it seems odd to assume away possible increases in incomes associated with a given tax reform proposal when its explicit goal is to enhance growth. This observation raises another reason that is given for excluding macro-dynamic effects—the impact of taxes on economic growth is uncertain. To be sure, there is a lot of disagreement on this issue among professional economists. But that is not sufficient cause to assume that the right answer is exactly zero. Rather, a more sensible approach is to consider alternative assumptions about how tax reform might affect the size of the economy, and see how they affect the substantive conclusions. As explained in the next section, this is the tack that I take. |
|
|