SOLVENCY: Monetary incentives to support school choice helps kids

MYTHCONCEPTIONS ABOUT SCHOOL CHOICE

 

 

     Many people worry that a free market approach to schooling, even with vouchers or scholarships for low income families, would have negative effects on education. It is to these people, who simply want the best for their children and their neighbors' children, that this page is directed. Read the criticisms of choice and vouchers, read the rebuttals, and decide for yourselves on the merits of school choice.
     Readers may also wish to visit the Criticism of Government Vouchers page, which addresses the view that government funding would interfere with the effective operation of an educational market.

Note: All indented text by Andrew Coulson.

Haves and Have-Nots

"Far from creating the positive qualities of healthy 'competition,' vouchers would build an uneven playing field and institutionalize a two-tier system of haves and have-nots. Harming public schools to improve private schools hurts individuals, as well as our society as a whole." --Minnesota Education Association (An NEA affiliate).

     No one has yet designed a system of education that would deliver a perfectly equal education to all children. At present, educational choice is concentrated among wealthier families, who can opt for private schooling, and who can more easily relocate to areas with better quality schools.  Poor inner city children, by contrast, are frequently stuck in dilapidated government school buildings and offered an abysmally poor education compared with their suburban counterparts. This is the baseline to which alternative forms of school governance must be compared.
     The question is thus, would vouchers or some other form of scholarships for low-income families reduce or enlarge the educational gap between rich and poor that exists in public schools. If we look at currently operating voucher programs, the answer is clear. Because these programs are compensatory in nature,  they award vouchers only to poor children, thereby increasing the range of educational choices open to low-income families, and reducing the education gap. From both an economic and an educational standpoint this approach offers the most promise for future voucher programs as well. A mounting body of evidence also shows that private schools help to reduce the socio-economic achievement gap, and help to increase the level of integration between racial and socio-economic groups within schools.
     None of the proposed tweaks to existing public school systems (such as higher funding or national curricula) can offer the range of benefits enjoyed in a free educational marketplace, and scholarships would allow all families to participate in that marketplace.

Separation of Church and State

Would government-funded educational scholarships violate the first amendment proscripiton against an establishment of religion if the scholarships could be redeemed by religious schools?

     On this issue, the jury, or rather the U.S. Supreme Court, is still out. Both proponents and critics of vouchers can cite Supreme Court precedents which favor their positions, but no definitive precedent has yet been set.
     Even if the First Amendment does not preclude vouchers, however, Americans must ask themselves if they feel it is right for citizens to be forced to subsidize religious education which may conflict with their beliefs. Wisconsin's state constitution specifically prohibits the compelled support of religious institutions, and the expansion of the Milwaukee voucher program to include religious schools was struck down by an appelate court as a violation of that clause--even though no particular religion was favored by the program. That verdict was subsequently appealed to the Supreme Court of Wisconsin, which reversed it--allowing the expansion of the voucher program to include religious schools. An appeal of the Wisconsin Supreme Court ruling was made to the US Supreme Court, but the high court refused to consider the case, allowing the Wisconsin Supreme Court verdict to stand.
     It must be remembered, however, that state and federal constitutional problems are only endemic to government voucher programs. One of the many advantages of privately-run and -funded scholarship programs is that they engender no such legal issues. Private voucher programs are thus superior in this respect to government programs.

Who Would do the Choosing?

"Vouchers fail to offer the 'choice' that proponents claim. The 'choice' remains with the private schools that will continue to pick and choose the students they wish to accept and reject. Public schools open their doors to all students." --Minnesota Education Association (An NEA affiliate).

     Once again, it is necessary to compare market-based school reforms with the status quo, rather than with a mythical ideal in which every family could obtain precisely the education it sought. At present, the vast majority of children are simply assigned to a public school, and have little choice in the matter. What voucher programs would do is allow those children a choice. While not every child will secure a place at his number one choice of school, his chances of finding a high-quality, appropriate educational environment will be vastly greater than under the present conformist state-run system. In Japan, the only nation with a thriving for-profit educational market, most private schools respond to pent-up demand by expanding their operations, rather than by turning away students--just as do for-profit enterprises in other industries. Supermarkets and bookstores do not put their customers on waiting lists, but rather expand their facilities to meet the demand.
     While non-profit private schools are considerably less responsive to fluctuations in demand than are their profit-making counterparts, even they offer students with a wider range of choices than government school systems. The National Catholic Education Association reports that almost three quarters of its schools accept roughly three quarters of their applicants--hardly a stringent selection process. Furthermore, many rejections are due to lack of space, a problem that would be reduced if vouchers were available to pay for new classrooms. An educational market supplemented with scholarships for low-income families would clearly improve the almost total lack of choice imposed on most families by the public school system.

Would Vouchers Drain Money
from Public Schools?

"Vouchers would further limit already tight financing that causes districts to use outdated textbooks, computers and other equipment, to increase class sizes and to scrimp on teachers." --Minnesota Education Association (An NEA affiliate).

     This is one of the most pernicious and flagrant of the anti-choice claims. To begin with, the overwhelming majority of public schools are not underfunded, including those in depressed, inner-city areas. While there are some poorly funded districts scattered around the country, low funding is not the chief cause of decaying facilities and moribund materials. Public school per-pupil spending, taking inflation into account, is now 14 times higher than it was 70 years ago. On average, public schools now spend close to $7,000 per student per year, twice the average at private schools. In some inner-city public school districts, such as Hartford, Connecticut, Washington, D.C., Baltimore, Maryland, etc. an annual outlay of roughly $9,000 per pupil is so poorly managed that many schools are falling apart and failing even to supply their own bathrooms with toilet paper.
     Statistics published by the NCES reveal that the 300 largest big-city school districts spend roughly the same amount per pupil as the average of all 15,000+ districts in the United States. Studies of inner-city Catholic schools demonstrate that low-income students can learn more at far less cost, and in far safer and more agreeable surroundings in the private sector. The fact that government school equipment and facilities are deteriorating or have become outdated is most often a sign of mismanagement, not lack of funds.
     The financial effects of vouchers, even vouchers for the full per-pupil expenditure of public schools, should be negligible. For every decrease in the amount of funds directed to public schools, there would be a commensurate reduction in the work load and hence costs of operating public schools. If a given public school was so bad as to see an exodus of all its pupils, it could be shut down and its buildings leased or sold, actually generating income.
     Few voucher proponents have suggested vouchers equal to the full cost of public schooling, however. Most offer or recommend vouchers in the range of $3,000. If students were given $3,000 vouchers, enough for most private elementary schools, they would be saving the public system an average of $4,000 per year! And even if some of that savings were returned to tax-payers, there would still be enough for yet another increase in public school expenditures, if that is what voters wanted.
     Why, then, would the teacher's unions oppose such programs? Because fewer public school students would mean a need for fewer public school teachers. Unions protect their members' jobs. That is what they are for and that is what they do. It would be naive to expect otherwise.

It's Academic

"Are vouchers an academic savior? Not in Milwaukee where academic results have been mixed, at best. According to a study by the University of Wisconsin-Madison, voucher student reading scores increased the first year, fell substantially the second and remained about the same the next two years. In math, voucher student scores were essentially the same the first and second year, rose in year three, and declined significantly the next year."--Minnesota Education Association (An NEA affiliate).

     Here the MEA and NEA are simply out of touch with the educational research community. Paul E. Peterson and Jiangtao Du of Harvard University, along with Jay P. Green of the University of Houston, recently led a statistical reanalysis of the public Milwaukee voucher experiment. They found that after three years in private schools, choice students showed greater gains in both reading and mathematics than those unfortunate students left behind in the public schools. Positive results continue to come in from other voucher programs.

Vouchers and Students Already in Private Schools

If vouchers were awarded to all parents, including the 11% of U.S. parents with children already enrolled in private schools, there would be an overall increase of 11% in education spending.

     This problem is easily avoided. Vouchers for students already in private schools could be phased in over time, and paid for entirely from the savings generated by the shift of children from government-run to independently-run schools. Furthermore, vouchers could be varied in size based on need, being cut-off above an agreed family income level: after all, there is little sense in taxing wealthy families to pay for their own children's education, when they could (and in many cases already do) pay for it themselves.
     Finally, even if the popular consensus was that every family should receive a voucher for the full value of their children's education, the system could still easily avoid increasing the overall tax burden. As is well known, public schools are notoriously inefficient when it comes to spending, costing more than existing private schools. As competition amongst private schools intensified, prices would no doubt drop even lower. The 11% difference would be more than made up for by these factors.

Voucher Costs Over Time

"A voucher system is likely to get more expensive over time as private schools raise tuition in response to government subsidies." --Connecticut Education Association (An NEA affiliate)

     A conspicuous case of the pot calling the kettle black. Public schools have raised their expenditures by a factor of fourteen over the last seventy odd years (even after adjusting for inflation), without demonstrating any substantial improvements in student educational achievement. In a competitive educational market, by contrast, any school that increased its tuition so wantonly would quickly loose customers to a more efficiently-run institution.
     Nevertheless, any system in which the government rather than the consumer pays the bills is susceptible to capture by special interests. Just as teachers' unions consistently (and successfully) lobby for higher educational spending to raise teachers' salaries, so government-funded vouchers would lead private school organizations to band together and lobby for larger vouchers. Since the school organizations would be organized on this issue, and since parents and other taxpayers are generally not organized, it is likely that vouchers would increase over time. How these increases would compare to the rapid growth we have already witnessed in public school spending is impossible to say. It is worthwhile to note that when consumers are responsible for paying their own way, lobbying is no longer possible: the only way you can lobby your own customers is to offer better services. This is why competitive market prices are generally lower than public (government) costs for similar services--existing private versus public schools are a case in point.

CONTEXT(Help)
-
Argumentation and Debate - 62242 »Argumentation and Debate - 62242
Greg Vander Kooy »Greg Vander Kooy
DEBATE 3 »DEBATE 3
Parents SHOULD have significantly more choice in their kids education »Parents SHOULD have significantly more choice in their kids education
PLAN; Government should increase support for parent choice in schools »PLAN; Government should increase support for parent choice in schools
SOLVENCY: Monetary incentives to support school choice helps kids
Gov support of vouchers increases competition between all schools »Gov support of vouchers increases competition between all schools
Monetary supports do not need to cost tax payers any MORE money »Monetary supports do not need to cost tax payers any MORE money
School VOUCHER programs have excellent results in helping kids »School VOUCHER programs have excellent results in helping kids
a plan that is fiscally neutral is something everyone can support »a plan that is fiscally neutral is something everyone can support
School VOUCHER programs have excellent results in helping kids »School VOUCHER programs have excellent results in helping kids
Programs which have good results are worth supporting »Programs which have good results are worth supporting
Better schools are what everyone wants & motivates parent involvement »Better schools are what everyone wants & motivates parent involvement
+Comments (0)
+Citations (0)
+About